The Valuation of Public Debt in the U.S. and Across Countries
Project Outcomes Statement
Our research project begins from the simple observation that a government's ability to issue debt is limited by its ability to eventually repay that debt. That fiscal capacity depends on the primary surpluses the country runs now and in the future. There is a simple analogy to the stock market: the equity value of a company equals the expected present discounted value of its current and future dividends it pays out to its shareholders. Likewise, the value of government debt equals the expected present discounted value of its current and future surpluses.
Our first paper "The U.S. Public Debt Valuation Puzzle,"writes down a realistic model for the primary surpluses, using historical data on tax revenues and government spending going back to 1946. It also writes down a realistic model for the discount rate used to compute the present value of those surpluses. We impose that the discount rate is consistent with the observed prices of government bonds of various maturitis as well as with the prices of U.S. stocks. The main finding of that paper is that the U.S. fiscal backing is surprisingly low: the present value of future surpluses is low because (1) the surpluses have been low over the past 75 years, and (2) the surpluses have been low in bad times. Investors who must absorb the additional debt in bad times require a risk premium to do so, just like they require a risk premium to hold stocks of firms that pay low dividends in bad times. The actual amount of debt the U.S. government is able to issue far exceeds our measure of fiscal backing. We call this large wedge, the difference between the market value of debt outstanding and the present value of surpluses, a puzzle. This puzzle remains even after the additional government revenue stream from convenience yields is considered.
We go on to explore various potential resolutions to the puzzle, ranging from a bubble (violation of a transversality condition), to the possibility that bond investors are pricing in a large reduction in future government spending or a large increase in future tax rates, to missing government assets. While it is hard to rule out these alternative explanations decisively, we come down on mispricing as our favorite explanation.
The paper "Fiscal Capacity: An Asset Pricing Perspective" provides a non-technical summary of our arguments. The paper "Measuring U.S. Fiscal Capacity using Discounted Cash Flow Analysis" applies these ideas using actual surplus forecasts from the Congressional Budget Office to quantify the fiscal capacity of the U.S. government as of now.
In "Exorbitant Privilege Gained and Lost: Fiscal Implications" we expand our analysis to other countries and to longer historical time periods. Specifically, we study the fiscal backing in the U.K going back to 1789 and in the Dutch Republic in the 17th and 18th centuries. We find that just like the U.S. appears to have excess borrowing capacity (be able to issue more debt than its fiscal backing) after 1946, so does the U.K. prior to 1946. Prior to 1946, the U.S. did not borrow more than the present value of its future surpluses, nor did the U.K after 1946. Bond investors bestow excess fiscal capacity onto a global hegemon. That role passed form the U.K. to the U.S. sometime between the first and the second World War. Prior to the U.K. the Dutch Republic was the hegemon, with ample borrowing capacity.
"Manufacturing Risk-free Government Debt" makes the point that, if policmakers insist on keeping government debt risk-free for bond investors (zero beta in the language of finance) then they must shift the risk onto taxpayers. The government cannot simultaneously insure taxpayers, by running large primary deficits in bad times, and insuring bondholders. If debt is risk-free, tax revenues must be risky, that is, they must increase in bad times.
In "Bond Convenience Yields in the Eurozone Currency Union" we study the implications of the relationship between debt and the present value of surpluses in a currency union like the Eurozone. We observe that a currency union has one common shrt-term interest rate, which cannot adjust in response to country-speciic fiscal shocks. Rather either default risk or convenience yields must act as fiscal shock absorbers. We show empirically that convenience yields in the Eurozone indeed seem to adjust when the fiscal position of a member country changes.
Investigators
Supported by the National Science Foundation grant #2049260
Related
Programs
More from NBER
In addition to working papers, the NBER disseminates affiliates’ latest findings through a range of free periodicals — the NBER Reporter, the NBER Digest, the Bulletin on Retirement and Disability, the Bulletin on Health, and the Bulletin on Entrepreneurship — as well as online conference reports, video lectures, and interviews.
- Feldstein Lecture
- Presenter: Cecilia E. Rouse
- Methods Lectures
- Presenter: Susan Athey